Fixing Healthcare, Part One: An Inventory of Cost-Containment

More

healthcare.JPG

For the past few weeks, I've been talking with healthcare experts with a variety of perspectives, trying to discover coherent principles for overhauling American healthcare. This requires, in my view, testing every idea against its likely effect on the real people who provide healthcare services and on the real people who need those services. What's ultimately required is to change the culture of healthcare delivery. 

 

Congress doesn't seem to be tethered to the realities of healthcare delivery, and its proposed bills seem to have been tossed in a storm of special interests. The refusal of the Democratic leadership to consider pilot projects for more reliable systems of justice--see my recent op-eds in the Wall Street Journal and Washington Post--is just one example of special interests trumping the needs of the common good. 

 

It's hard to put pressure on Congress without a coherent point of view of what a new system should look like. In the first part of this post, I describe the aspects of current healthcare that drive up costs and must be addressed by a new framework. In the second part, I describe a framework for reform which would provide universal coverage with incentives to contain costs. 

 

Part One: An Inventory of Cost-Containment                                                 

 

The healthcare debates have focused on ways to expand coverage--by mandates, by a public option, and by various forms of subsidy. But the underlying problem remains one of affordability, and, specifically, how to bring efficiency to a healthcare system notorious for its inefficiency. 

 

Few concrete solutions have emerged because the healthcare industry itself is not sure what to do--its economic model is the product of the bureaucratic reimbursement and regulatory framework that drives providers towards always doing more. Moreover, the Congressional Budget Office cannot "score" most proposed solutions because it is impossible to quantify with any precision the main drivers of inefficiency--for example, the fee-for-service delivery model, or the amount of defensive medicine--or to quantify the potential savings of changing the legal and reimbursement framework. 

 

Cost-containment can be viewed through many perspectives, which often overlap--for example, ineffective chronic care can be viewed in part as a problem of fee-for-service reimbursement. But categories of waste and inefficiency can nonetheless be identified, which any reform package should attempt to address. Here they are: 

 

1.      Chronic care.  Care for chronic illness--mainly diabetes and heart disease--accounts for roughly 75 percent of all healthcare costs. About half of this is attributable to obesity, smoking, and other bad habits. There are several potential ways of cutting these costs:

 

--First, create incentives and other programs for healthier lifestyles.  Safeway offers its employees reductions in premiums for losing weight and quitting smoking.

 

--Second, change the model of care delivery, from fee-for-service to a capitated "medical home" (or "accountable care organization"), in which providers are paid so much per patient per year, with incentives to push patients towards healthier lifestyles and with pay-for-performance adjustments to reward providers who succeed. There was a discussion among leading experts at NewTalk.org. Much of this work requires the work of social workers, not expensive healthcare professionals. Most experts agree on the need to shift to a medical home model; there is less agreement on how to get there.

 

2.      End-of-life care. Nearly one-third of Medicare's yearly expenditures are on patients in the last year of their lives. There is a wide disparity in care for terminal illness, especially for the elderly. Palliative care in a home or hospice setting is often the most humane solution, but many doctors feel compelled to try to "cure" old age with dramatic and expensive interventions. Sometimes these are driven by an insistent child, sometimes by fear of lawsuits, sometimes by medical self-interest. Professor Marshall Kapp and Dr. Diane Meier review some of these problems.

 

The solution to inappropriate interventions at the end of life is not to put government in the position of making life and death decisions. But there must be a reliable legal framework in which doctors feel comfortable offering ethical leadership in end-of-life situations. Third Way provides an excellent summary of the situation and its solutions. Committee for Economic Development (CED) fostered a discussion on its sponsored 2007 proposal, beginning on p. 38. 

 

3.    Over-treatment. The pioneering work at Dartmouth by Dr. John Wennberg and colleagues exposed the inconvenient fact that healthcare is often driven by supply of doctors and machines, not by need for care. Costs in Florida are almost double that in Minnesota, with no better outcomes. The recent report in the New Yorker by Dr. Atul Gawande revealed that costs in McAllen, Texas are almost double that in El Paso, with no better results. The cost driver appeared to be that doctors in McAllen had become entrepreneurs, setting up their own clinics, buying expensive diagnostic equipment and then giving their patients the works--paid for by the clunky fee-for-service reimbursement schedules.  

 

The solutions for over-treatment include:        

 

--Change the reimbursement model for primary care and chronic care, migrating from fee-for-service to a capitation model with pay-for-performance adjustments. To avoid under-treatment, there needs to be end-of-year audits to review effectiveness. The CED report sited above provides descriptions of successful models, starting on p. 41. Making this transition is unavoidably complex. The best approach, which is embodied in various proposals but not in a simplified form, is to provide a voucher redeemable at a "health exchange," offering annual coverage at a fixed price. This has the enormous potential advantage of driving insurers and providers to a capitation-based model of delivery for the simple reason that fee-for-service providers will become uncompetitive. I discuss this in the second part of this post.

Jump to comments
Presented by

Philip K. Howard is a lawyer, author and chair of Common Good. He is the author, most recently, of Life Without Lawyers: Restoring Responsibility in America, and wrote the introduction to Al Gore's Common Sense Government. More

Philip K. Howard is the author of Life Without Lawyers(Norton 2009), as well as the best-seller The Death of Common Sense(Random House, 1995) and The Collapse of the Common Good(Ballantine, 2002), and he is a periodic contributor to the op-ed pages of The New York Times, The Wall Street Journal, and The Washington Post. He advises leaders of both parties on legal and regulatory reform issues, and wrote the introduction to Vice President Al Gore's book Common Sense Government. A practicing lawyer, Howard is a partner in the law firm Covington & Burling LLP. In 2002, Howard founded Common Good (www.commongood.org), organized to restore common sense to American public life. The Advisory Board of Common Good is composed of leaders from a broad cross-section of American political thought including, among others, former Senators Howard Baker, Bill Bradley, George McGovern, and Alan Simpson. Howard is a civic leader in New York and is Chair-Emeritus of the Municipal Art Society, a leading civic group that spearheaded initiatives to preserve Grand Central Terminal.
Get Today's Top Stories in Your Inbox (preview)

The Ghost Trains of America

Can a band of locomotive experts save vintage railcars from ruin?


Elsewhere on the web

Join the Discussion

After you comment, click Post. If you’re not already logged in you will be asked to log in or register. blog comments powered by Disqus

Video

Why Did I Study Physics?

Using hand-drawn cartoons to explain an academic passion

Video

What If Emoji Lived Among Us?

A whimsical ad imagines what life would be like if emoji were real.

Video

Living Alone on a Sailboat

"If you think I'm a dirtbag, then you don't understand the lifestyle."

Video

How Is Social Media Changing Journalism?

How new platforms are transforming radio, TV, print, and digital

Video

The Place Where Silent Movies Sing

How an antique, wind-powered pipe organ brings films to life

Feature

The Future of Iced Coffee

Are artisan businesses like Blue Bottle doomed to fail when they go mainstream?

Writers

Up
Down

More in National

From This Author

Just In